5 Comments

Thank you for redoing this for 2022.

Expand full comment

It was a good learning experience for teaching myself how to use Excel 😅

Expand full comment

Do you have anything on the fiscal impact of immigrants? Some studies I've seen show a positive fiscal impact from them, especially from illegals

Expand full comment

I know that Cato often gets cited to show how nice migrants are for the economy. The way they measure fiscal impact is interesting. Normally, what people think of when they think of "welfare" is just means-tested welfare. Cato adds Social Security and Medicare in as their list of welfare (which migrants use less for very obvious reasons). Their justification for this is that those technically are part of government spending and you can't just cherrypick what to include and what to exclude. So, fine, as you can tell from my analysis, government usage also includes Social Security and Medicare, but it also includes other things such as stuff related to law enforcement and public transit, because hey, if we're going to use that logic, might as well go all the way, right? Another thing: Cato uses the ASEC from the Current Population Survey, which isn't bad, it's generally recognized by economists, but it does have a tendency to underestimate welfare use disproportionately for migrants and that's why CIS uses the SIPP instead (see: https://cis.org/Report/Cost-Welfare-Use-Immigrant-and-Native-Households). The reason why the March CPS gets used is because it’s got a much larger sample size and allows you to run state and local analyses. Oh also, they count the children of immigrants as natives, so all their burden gets assigned to natives as well. Again, they have justifications for it, just not very good ones, especially since people who actually understand this care about race and not the legal status, the legal status isn't some magical wand that suddenly turns poor dumb people from failed states into elite human capital.

Aside from Cato, there are studies that use the general equilibrium model rather than generational accounting in order to factor in indirect benefits/costs. It's a noble effort but those papers are usually not great because they are laden with so many assumptions, some of which are certainly not safe ones at all, so their estimates usually all end up being hard to take seriously. Mainstream economists can't even get the basics right. Here's one: immigration and wages. Is there an effect? Lots of economists say no, but that's just because shift-share instruments, a commonly employed method, captures both the immediate shock from the new wave of migrants and the catch-up effect from previous waves of migrants, so they always understate the negative effect (see: https://www.nber.org/papers/w24285). Or, another problem: natives hurt by migration relocate elsewhere, of course you can just pretend there's no effect if the people who were hurt left (see: https://sci-hub.se/10.1086/713148 and https://drive.google.com/file/d/19r6QhTIkSaF4tQIvlkEndlexWHKz3ARb/view). Okay, so the average economist can’t even measure the effect on wages correctly. Moreover, if we’re going to try to model the indirect side of things, we’re going to have to zoom out a lot more because there’s a whole lot of externalities to be accounted for from National IQ on well-being beyond the individuals themselves (see: https://openpsych.net/files/papers/Kirkegaard_2014e.pdf). Anyways, I just wouldn't take those seriously. You can also read this piece, might be of interest: https://www.sebjenseb.net/p/the-case-for-border-control

Expand full comment

Great breakdown, have read the older version done, but the change of whites positioned is quite stark. My finger is on that the aging and disabled population increased, since whites are more top-heavy age wise in the US (well, everywhere).

Also nicely done on the topic of yellow fever.

Expand full comment